Money, Markets, and
Mobility: Celebrating the Ideas of Robert A.
Mundell Nobel Laureate in Economic Sciences
Thomas J. Courchene (ed.),
2002 (Paper ISBN: 0-88911-820-5
$22.95) (Cloth ISBN: 0-88911-818-3 $55.00)
Jump to
Contents | |
Introduction | |
Acknowledgement | . . . | ix |
Homage to Robert Alexander Mundell: |
|
|
Introduction |
|
|
I: The 1999 Nobel Lecture in Economic Sciences | ||
A Reconsideration of the Twentieth Century Robert A. Mundell |
|
|
II: Optimum Currency Areas: Analytical Perspectives | ||
Mundell, the Euro and Optimum Currency Areas Ronald McKinnon |
|
|
The New Economy and the Exchange Rate Regime Richard G. Harris |
|
|
III: Optimum Currency Areas: Empirical Perspectives | ||
Exchange Rate Flexibility and Monetary Policy Choice for Emerging Market Economies Michael B. Devereux and Philip R. Lane |
|
|
IV: The Macro Mix | ||
Reflections on the Mundell-Fleming Model on its Fortieth Anniversary Russell S. Boyer |
. . . |
|
Problems of Monetary and Exchange-Rate Management in Canada Pierre Fortin |
. . . |
139 |
V: Real Trade Theory | ||
Factor Flows: Immigration in a Specific Factor Framework James R. Melvin and Robert Waschik |
. . . |
165 |
VI: International Economy | ||
Perspectives on the Evolution of the Global Trading System Sylvia Ostry |
. . . |
197 |
VII: North American Currency Integration: Policy Panel | ||
Engaging the Debate: Costs and Benefits of a North American Common Currency John McCallum |
. . . |
227 |
Toward North American Monetary Union Herbert Grubel |
. . . |
245 |
Unilateral and Multilateral Currency Integration: Reflections on Western Hemispheric Monetary Union George M. von Furstenberg |
. . . |
253 |
VIII: The Future of National Currencies | ||
Exchange Rate Systems and Currency Integration: Prospects for the Twenty-First Century Robert A. Mundell |
. . . |
269 |
Appendix | ||
A Plan for a European Currency Robert A. Mundell |
. . . |
295 |
Contributors |
Return to Top |
INTRODUCTION
Robert A. Mundell - Canada's Nobel Laureate
In this volume we honour the magnificent contributions of Robert A.
Mundell, arguably the foremost postwar thinker in international
macro-economics and the global monetary order. Mundell was not the first
Canadian to win a Nobel Prize in Economics and he will not be the last.
But his Nobel Prize is surely a quintessentially "Canadian" Nobel Prize
in
the sense that his intellectual achievements are closely allied with the
challenges that Canada, as a small open economy, faces in the global
economic order - domestic and external balance, perfect capital
mobility,
fixed versus flexible exchange rates, optimal currency areas and the
like.
What Mundell perceived, and what few others did, was that all economies
in our progressively global and mobile world would eventually take on
the
then-distinguishing features of the Canadian economy. Hence, we as
Canadians can take special pride in his Nobel Prize since his
accomplishments are to an important degree routed in his Canadianness -
and this is apart from the fact that he has maintained his close
Canadian
ties and citizenship.
Queen's University is especially proud of Mundell's achievement
as
he is a Kingston native. Indeed, this conference celebrates not only
Robert Mundell's Nobel Prize but, Queen's conferring on him an Honorary
Doctor of Laws.
The role of this introduction is to focus briefly on selected
aspects of Bob Mundell's career and, then, to present a brief outline of
the volume.
Robert Mundell: A Profile
Robert A. Mundell was born in 1932 in Latimer, Ontario, essentially a
crossroads near Loughborough Lake on the outskirts of Kingston. On the
occasion of his delivering Queen's School of Policy Studies' inaugural
Gibson Lecture in 1990, Bob and his wife Valerie and I finally managed
to
locate Latimer's abandoned one-room schoolhouse that Mundell asserts was
so central to his intellectual formation. In his typically mischievous
way, he claims he never really went to grade one: rather, he was able to
pick and choose simultaneously from the offering of grades one through
eight.
In 1945, the Mundell family moved to Kingston - actually to the
Gate House of the Royal Military College since Bob's father was in the
army - and Bob took his first year of high school at Kingston Collegiate
Vocational Institute. Bob's father retired from the army during this
year
and the Mundell family moved west to British Columbia, where Bob
completed
high school and, later, graduated from the University of British
Columbia.
He began his graduate work at the University of Washington, then
continued at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology (MIT) and the
London School of Economics, receiving his PhD in 1956 from MIT. Then
began
a series of short-term professorships across North America and Europe -
to
Chicago in 1956-57 as a post-doctoral fellow, then back to UBC for a
year
and on to Stanford in 1958-59 and the Bologna Institute for Advanced
International Studies for 1959-61 before joining the staff of the
International Monetary Fund (IMF) in 1961. His time at the LSE
introduced
him to James Meade and his writings which, combined with his Bologna
experience, enabled Mundell to observe first hand both the introduction
of
the Common Market in 1956 and the Treaty of Rome in 1958, events whose
trajectory he would eventually influence as the "intellectual godfather"
of the euro. And, of course, his IMF years introduced him to Marcus
Fleming, the Deputy Director of the Research Department of the IMF.
By 1963 Bob was back in Canada (McGill) for a year, then off to
the Brookings Institution in Washington, DC for 1964-65 and finally to
the
University of Chicago, where he stayed long enough (1966-71) to develop
the what might be termed the Mundell School of "open-economy
macro-economics", many of the disciples of which have gone on to achieve
renown on their own.
While I am not a Chicago PhD, I did have the incredible good
fortune to have been a Chicago post-doctoral student in 1968-69 and to
get
to know Bob and his work during these creative Chicago years. Chicago's
senior faculty were simply grand - among them Friedman, Harberger,
Becker,
Zellner, Fogel and Coase. International economics was held down by two
Canadians: Mundell and Harry Johnson. Harry's lectures were, at one
level,
a student's delight. The anlytical core of each topic was carefully
developed and then all of the relevant recent literature was integrated
into this core - a tour de force, to be sure, but one that
typically left
a student believing that there were precious few loose ends that would
provide topics for theses. Bob was exactly the opposite, at least from
my
limited experience. Mundell would walk into class and present the
students
with an interesting issue or challenge (sometimes the issue came from
the
class) and then would proceed to develop a model to tackle it, or at
least
get the model up and running more or less in the right direction. In the
process of this modelling, the air was ripe with thesis topics. Our late
Queen's colleague, Doug Purvis, himself a leading Chicago School
disciple
until his tragic death in 1993, pursued what was likely the optimal
strategy - get your ideas from Bob, but write your thesis under
Harry!
In 1972, Mundell was again back in Canada, this time as Chair of
Waterloo's Economics Department. Finally, in 1974, Bob went to Columbia
which, apart from short-term visitorships, has remained his intellectual
home to this day. As the Nobel Website notes, these visitorships since
moving to Columbia included: the Annenberg Professor of Communications
at
USC in 1980; the Repap Professor of Economics at McGill in 1989-90;
Richard Fox Professor of Economics at the University of Pennsylvania in
1990-91; and a return visit to Bologna in 1997-98. Along the way Bob has
received the Guggenheim Prize in 1971, the Jacques Rueff Medal in 1983,
the AEA Distinguished Fellow Award in 1997, and he became a Fellow of
the
America Academy of Arts and Sciences in 1998. Post Nobel Prize, Robert
Mundell has received honorary degrees from numerous universities
world-wide, including, of course, Queen's University.
While the above Nobel Prize Press Release from The Royal Swedish
Academy of Sciences focuses largely on Mundell's contributions from his
pre-Columbia period, he has continued to have a remarkably influential
career. One of his recent achievements has already been alluded to: his
campaign for a single European currency and, more generally, for
currency
reform in Canada and elsewhere. I need not stress his key and early
analytical role in the introduction of the euro. Suffice it to say that
although his Nobel Prize was long overdue, it is entirely fitting that
Bob
won the prize in the year that the euro was inaugurated.
Closer to home, Bob's 1990 paper "The Overvalued Canadian
Dollar"
represents one of the early contributions in the direction of raising
the
issue of exchange-rate fixity and monetary union between the United
States
and Canada. He has followed this with dozens of interviews, articles and
public appearances in support of currency consolidation in the
Americas.
Among his other recent contributions, the most impressive and
most
far-reaching would surely have to be his role as the intellectual force
behind the "supply-side revolution". This was a natural for Bob in the
sense that this was a macro-mix issue. Mundell's recipe, adopted by
President Ronald Reagan (with the help of Jack Kemp and others) was that
the appropriate macro mix was tight money to control inflation and tax
cuts to stimulate growth. It is important to note in this context that
the
top marginal personal income tax rate in the United States in 1979 was
70%. During the Reagan years, this was reduced to 28% (there is a brief
33% tax rate while the personal exceptions are taxed back). It is also
important not to minimize the "demonstration effect" abroad of this U.S.
tax cut. Indeed, the sweep of this global revolution is such that I am
sure that there is not a single developed country where top marginal tax
rates have not been lowered substantially. And Canada is no exception.
While the combination of the Nobel press release and the above
review of some of the other major milestones hopefully serves as an
appropriate tour d'horizon of Robert Mundell's intellectual
career, it
nonetheless misses much of what Mundell the person is all about. His
interests have always transcended economics. He has always been a keen
student of philosophy (how else would we know that Plato was a hard
currency advocate, while Aristotle a soft-currency man?). Likewise for
history (how else would we know that the looting of Constantinople in
1203
led to the proliferation of fluctuating exchange rates in the middle
ages?). Bob is also an accomplished painter. No doubt it was this
combination of history and art and philosophy that played a role in his
devoting considerable effort over the last 25 years or so to rebuilding
and restoring a twelfth-century Medici castle in Tuscany, Santa Columba,
more recently called Palazzo Mundell. His Website is liberally sprinkled
with pictures of his wife Valerie Natsios and their young son Nicholas,
usually with Palazzo Mundell as backdrop.
Mundell remains devilishly young at heart, always good humoured
and, as his student Rudi Dornbusch notes, he often comes across as a
good
natured enfant terrible. Indeed, at the Nobel Prize award
ceremony, and
again at his Queen's Honorary Degree ceremony, Bob concluded his
respective addresses with a rendition of "I Did It My Way".
Outline of Money, Markets and Mobility ...
Beyond the formal recognition of an Honorary Doctor of Laws from
Queen's,
our way to celebrate Mundell's achievements was to hold a
conference in
his honour and to publish the Festschrift. An annotated outline
of this
celebratory volume follows.
Mundell's Nobel Lecture
Thanks to the Nobel Foundation and to Mundell, the volume appropriately
begins with Bob's Nobel Prize Lecture. Recognizing that his was the last
Nobel Prize in Economics in the twentieth century and with his typical
flair for the dramatic, Mundell entitled his lecture A
Reconsideration
of
the Twentieth Century. He divides the century into three distinct
and
almost equal parts. The first part, 1900-33, is the story of the
international gold standard, its breakdown during World War I, its
managed
restoration in the 1920s and its demise in the early 1930s. The second
part, 1934-71, begins with the devaluation of the dollar and the
establishment of the $35 gold price and ends when the United States took
the dollar off gold. The third part of the century, 1972-99, starts with
the move to flexible exchange rates and continues with the subsequent
outbreak of massive inflation and stagnation in the 1970s, the
blossoming
of supply-side economics in the 1980s, and the return to monetary
stability and the birth of the euro in the 1990s.
In Mundell's view, the twentieth century ended with an
international monetary system inferior to that with which it began. In
the
penultimate paragraph he elaborates as follows:
Today, the dollar, the euro and yen have established three
islands
of monetary stability, which is a great improvement over the 1970s and
1980s. There are, however, two pieces of unfinished business. The most
important is the dysfunctional volatility of exchange rates that could
sour international relations in time of crisis. The other is the absence
of an international currency.
Fortunately, in the final paper in the volume, Mundell addresses this
"unfinished business".
McKinnon on Optimum Currency Areas
The Nobel Prize Lecture aside, our Mundell Festschrift begins
with an
analytical focus on optimum currency areas (OCA). The author, Stanford's
Ronald McKinnon, is ideally suited to delve into this issue since his
own
American Economic Review article "Optimum Currency Areas"
(September 1963,
pp. 717-725) remains a key contribution to the development of the OCA
literature. McKinnon's role here is to try to marry the two Mundells, as
it were - the Mundell of the seminal 1961 AER paper and the Mundell who
later was hailed, as already noted, as the godfather of the euro. As
McKinnon emphasizes, the key to bridging these two Mundells lies in two
rather obscure articles presented at a 1970 conference in Madrid and
published in the conference volume edited by H.G. Johnson and A.K.
Swoboda, The Economics of Common Currencies (1973). As McKinnon
elaborates, the more analytical of these two articles notes that a
country
suffering an adverse shock can better share the loss with a trading
partner if both countries hold claims on each other's output in a common
currency. If, however, a country holds its claims in its own currency
and
devalues in response to an adverse shock, it then absorbs the loss
itself.
The more policy oriented of the two is entitled A Plan for a
European
Currency and it is one of Mundell's first papers arguing for a
common
European currency. Because Mundell's role in the evolution of the euro
is
not well known or understood, I have (following Ron McKinnon's
suggestion)
included A Plan for a European Currency as an Appendix to this
volume.
Harris on Open Economy Endogenous Growth
Richard Harris' "The New Economy and the Exchange Rate Regime" is, in an
important sense, the most Mundellian of the contributions in this
volume.
Essentially, Harris takes the endogenous growth model and proceeds to
internationalize it in the context of both fixed and flexible
exchange-rate regimes. In an economy with two sectors - an old
(resource-based) economy and a new (human-capital/information-based)
economy - Harris focuses on the implications for productivity under both
fixed and flexible rate regimes when the economy is hit by two shocks: a
fall in prices in the old economy (e.g., a fall in resource prices) and
the advent of a new general purpose technology (GPT) which presents new
opportunities for productivity increases. The results of the analysis
are
striking. If flexible rates are used to buffer (i.e., offset) the fall
in
commodity/resources prices, productivity falls for two reasons: (i) more
labour and capital remains employed in the old, lower productivity
economy
and (ii) the home country price of the GPT rises in tandem with the
depreciating home currency and, therefore, its adoption becomes less
pervasive. In contrast, a non-buffered economy (i.e., a
fixed-exchange-rate regime) experiences higher productivity in response
to
the two external shocks because more labour and capital shifts from the
old to the new economy and because the GPT is less expensive, both
relative to a buffering scenario. In addition to making an important
contribution to the optimal currency area debate, Harris' model is
likely
to trigger a lively literature in the general area of open-economy,
endogenous-growth models.
Devereux/Lane on International Macro Simulation
The paper by Michael Devereux and Philip Lane, "Exchange Rate
Flexibility
and Monetary Policy Choice for Emerging Market Economies", is a
convenient bridge between the previous two papers on optimal currency
areas and the later session on open-economy macro models. Drawing on one
of the results of the Mundell-Fleming model, namely that if the economy
is
subject to foreign disturbances such as real interest rates or demand
shocks, then it is better to let the exchange rate adjust so as to
cushion
the effect of the shock, Devereux-Lane paramaterize an open-economy
model
to address the issue of whether developing economies would be better off
with fixed or flexible exchange rates in the face of those foreign
shocks.
The authors compare fixed exchange rates with four variants of flexible
rates - a money growth rule, a price stability rate, a Taylor rule
(targeting inflation and output) and an optimal policy rule (defined as
adjusting either money or interest rates to ensure that the domestic
price
of non-traded goods equals marginal cost). The conclusions of the
simulation suggest that more exchange-rate variability is necessary than
is typically allowed within the usual operating rules for monetary
policy.
The authors recognize that their model ignores shocks emanating from the
domestic financial system which, in turn, may place limitations on the
ability to conduct monetary targeting as an operating rule. Moreover,
the
model ignores the reality that developing countries typically cannot
issue
marketable debt in their own currencies, which also may constrain
exchange-rate operations. Nevertheless, as these simulation models
embrace
more and more characteristics of the real world they will be
increasingly
able to provide important benchmarking in terms of what to expect from
alternative exchange-rate regimes for small, open economies in an
integrating global economic order.
Boyer on the Mundell-Fleming Model
Noting that the May 2000 Conference in honour of Mundell was the
fortieth
anniversary of the origins of the Mundell-Fleming model, Russell Boyer
elects to focus his paper on the manner in which the Mundell-Fleming
model
developed over the 1960-63 period, drawing from Mundell (1960), (1961a),
(1961b), Fleming (1962) and, finally, Mundell's classic perfect capital
mobility article in 1963. Boyer begins by developing the general
framework
that underlies both the Mundell and Fleming contributions and presents
the
implications for the macro mix under both exchange-rate regimes. He then
takes us through Mundell's modifications to this basic model - first,
shifting the definition of monetary policy from (a) a given level of the
money supply to (b) maintaining a constant rate of interest and finally
to
(c) an open market operation or the change in central bank domestic
assets
in the context of a definition of money consisting of both foreign and
domestic assets and, second and simultaneously, effectively increasing
the
degree of capital mobility until the familiar FF (external balance)
curve
becomes horizontal in r-Y space. While the punch line is well known -
monetary policy is potent under flexible exchange rates but ineffective
under fixed rates (and vice versa for fiscal policy) - the evolution of
the model is both instructive and fascinating. As Boyer notes, the
elegance and power of the Mundell analysis not only led to its immediate
adoption but as well its longevity, ample evidence for which is that "as
a
device for expounding the effects of macroeconomic policies, the Mundell
model diagram is still unsurpassed at the undergraduate textbook level".
Boyer adds that this is proof positive of Mundell's dictum - hard
writing
makes easy reading.
Fortin on the Macro Mix
In 1964, Bob Mundell published "Problems of Monetary and Exchange Rate
Management in Canada" in the National Bank Review. This article
constituted an assessment of Canadian macro policy in light of Bob's
classic papers on monetary and fiscal policies under fixed and
fluctuating
exchange rates, highlighted in the Boyer paper. Fortin opts to use this
same title to direct attention to some key Canadian macro-policy issues
in
the current time frame. He starts from an intriguing premise. Given that
he, along with Mundell and others, believes that a North American
Monetary
Union is the preferable long-term future for the Canadian currency but
is
an unacceptable option over the nearer term, the critical policy issue
then becomes one of improving the theory and practice of monetary and
exchange-rate management. Toward this end, he addresses three broad
questions: Has the inflation target been too low? Has actual output
tended
on average to be too much below potential output? Have monetary
conditions
become harder to manage? While Fortin answers all three questions in the
affirmative, this is vintage Fortin in that much of the richness and
insight of the analysis lies in the process of getting to "yes".
Melvin/Waschik on Real Trade and Factor Mobility
In all the excitement about Mundell's contributions to international
money
and macro policy - optimal currency areas, perfect capital mobility,
fixed
versus flexible exchange rates, the macro mix, and more recently, the
euro
and supply-side economics - it is easy to forget that Bob began his
career
as a trade theorist. James Melvin and Robert Waschik not only remind us
of
Bob's trade theory work, but they motivate their own contribution
"Factor
Flows: Immigration in a Specific Factor Framework" by drawing on
Mundell's
1957 influential American Economic Review article,
"International Trade
and Factor Mobility". The starting point of the Melvin-Waschik analysis
is
Mundell's result that, under certain assumptions, commodity trade and
factor mobility are substitutes in the sense that both lead to the same
trade equilibrium, namely that all factors will receive the same real
incomes. It is also well-known that the so-called specific-factor models
represent one case where factor-price equalization will not hold. (The
specific-factor model employed by Melvin and Waschik is one where the
production of both goods requires labour, but one also requires land
while
the other also requires capital.) Accordingly, Melvin and Waschik
utilize
a specific-factor model and explore the extent to which factor prices
can
differ. The results are quite dramatic. In one of their examples, wages
in
autarky in the home country are nine times that of the foreign country.
However, commodity trade increases the disparity to 11 times! With
labour
mobility, wages will be equalized - they fall to 23% of autarky levels
in
the home country and they double in the foreign country. For both
countries, a full equilibrium with trade and factor mobility is
preferred
to migration only. Given that the returns to the specific factors are
also
affected differentially by trade and by factor mobility, this has the
obvious potential for political conflict between labour and the specific
factors in terms of how far to pursue trade in goods and/or in
factors.
Ostry on the Evolution of the Global Trading Order
No volume focusing on money, markets and mobility would be anywhere near
comprehensive without some analysis of the evolution of those
supranational institutions primarily responsible for freeing up trade in
goods and services. Sylvia Ostry's "Perspectives on the Evolution of the
Global Trading System", precisely and ideally fills the bill. Ostry
begins
by noting that the Uruguay Round and its creation, the World Trade
Organization (WTO), embraced a series of "new issues" that have one
common
factor: they involve not only the border barriers or "shallow
integration"
of the original General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) but, also
and primarily, the domestic policy reconciliation or "deeper
integration"
of the WTO. Phrased differently, the negative integration (the
"thou shalt
nots") of GATT has given way to the positive integration of the
WTO, in
effect requiring reconfiguring of domestic infrastructure in terms of
governance, legal systems, regulatory systems and the like.
Intriguingly,
corresponding to the "new issues" are a series of "new players" such as
Internet-driven non-governmental organizations (NGOs). Accordingly, and
appropriately, a major part of Ostry's analysis is devoted to
elaborating
on the three broad roles for, or types of, NGOs: "mobilization networks"
whose chief objective is to rally support for a specific set of
activities; "technical networks" designed to provide specific
information
related to WTO issues; and a "virtual-secretariat" role to inform and to
assist developing countries in their WTO relationships. Thus, further
progress in freeing international trade in goods and services requires
directing attention to both institutional/structural issues and to
policy
issues. Sylvia Ostry opts more for the latter when she concludes that
where there is a political will there is a policy way, which she hopes
will soon lead to a serious rethinking of global policy.
McCallum, Grubel and von Furstenberg on
Common Currencies
Setting aside the Nobel Prize Lecture, the volume began with some
analytical perspectives relating to optimal currency areas and currency
consolidation. The two concluding sections return to this theme, the
first
of which is in the form of a policy roundtable focusing on the pros and
cons of a North American common currency.
John McCallum (then with the Royal Bank, now the Secretary of
State for International Financial Institutions) opens the roundtable
with
"Engaging the Debate: Costs and Benefits of a North American Common
Currency". For McCallum, a North American common currency means either
dollarization or a currency board: he rejects any option based on a
North
American version of the euro. After he further rejects dollarization as
politically unacceptable and a currency board as a slippery slope toward
dollarization, McCallum is left with flexible rates, and the core of his
contribution is basically a defence of the floating-rate status
quo on
grounds of sovereignty and policy flexibility, on the one hand, and a
dismissal of the common currency arguments that flexible rates have
undermined living standards and reduced Canadian productivity relative
to
the United States, on the other.
Herbert Grubel is one of the most ardent proponents of
Canada-U.S.
currency integration. In his paper, "Toward North American Monetary
Union", Grubel focuses on some of the new and/or lower profile
rationales
for monetary union (implicitly directing the reader to his 1999 Fraser
Institute publication for more mainstream rationales). One of his
principal arguments is that the degree of labour-market flexibility and
the nature of adjustment mechanisms are not independent of the
exchange-rate regime. Specifically, Grubel argues that the removal of
the
exchange rate as a shock absorber would lead to much enhanced
labour-market and institutional flexibility: indeed the famous European
Commission report, One Market, One Money argued that monetary
union would
enhance labour market flexibility. The upshot of all of this, according
to
Grubel, is that those empirical studies that suggest that shocks are
difficult to accommodate under fixed exchange rates must be seriously
discounted if the data they rely on were generated under flexible rates.
As a concluding comment, Grubel notes that the wholesale acceptance of
the
Keynesian assumption of downward rigid wages led to inflation and
deficits
as solutions to unemployment. Now that price stability and balanced
budgets have triumphed over inflation and deficit financing, attention
has
turned to the importance of flexible rates to deal with unemployment and
imperfect labour market flexibility. Grubel's parting shot is that the
time has come for exchange-rate flexibility to join inflation and
deficits
on the scrap heap of policies inspired by Keynesian economics.
In "Unilateral and Multilateral Currency Integration:
Reflections
on Western Hemispheric Monetary Union", George von Furstenberg broadens
the discussion beyond a Canada-U.S. currency union. His view is that
while
dollarization may be a useful immediate option for some countries in our
hemisphere, it is a second-best option in the short run and
unsustainable
in the long run. This long-run unsustainability will arise because if
the
option of monetary union is not available, then rather than losing
seigniorage indefinitely countries will, in tandem, reclaim co-ownership
and co-management of their monetary assets in a multilateral monetary
union with like-minded countries. The Americans could attempt to counter
this somewhat by making dollarization more attractive, for example, by
returning some of the seigniorage to the dollarizing country. But even
this will unlikely be enough. Von Furstenberg concludes that eventually
dollarization (or unilateral monetary union as he calls it) will be
doomed
and destabilizing unless it evolves toward a multilateral form from
within. Hence, his policy recommendation is that it is time for the
United
States to take a careful look at Europe's multilateral model of monetary
union and to develop a variant that could become beneficial for the
western hemisphere as a whole.
Mundell on Currency Evolution
It is entirely fitting that Bob Mundell has the last word, specifically
"Exchange Rate Systems and Currency Integration: Prospects for the
Twenty-First Century". This paper fulfills two roles. Firstly, it is a
natural extension and elaboration of the series of issues dealt with by
McCallum, Grubel and von Furstenberg. Secondly, it is a perfect
"bookend"
to Mundell's Nobel Lecture. The latter paper (and century) essentially
ends with the introduction of the euro in 1999 whereas this paper begins
with the advent of the euro and what this might augur for the
twenty-first
century. The analysis is far reaching, focusing as it does on
alternative
approaches to currency integration, on alternative approaches to
monetary
rules, on the pros and cons of dollarization and its alternatives from a
Canadian perspective, on the need for both external and internal
stability
and, finally, on the advantages of a world currency. His concluding
paragraph is instructive:
The link between language and currency has often been noted.
Language is a medium of communication and currency is a medium of
exchange. National, ethnic and liturgical languages are here to stay,
but
a common world language, understood as a second language everywhere,
would
obviously facilitate international understanding. By the same token,
national or regional currencies will be with us for a long time in the
next centuries, but a common world currency, understood as the second
most
important currency in every country, in which values could be
com-municated and payments made everywhere, would be a magnificent step
toward increased prosperity and improved international organization.
* * *
All that remains is for me to express my sincerest thanks, as
well
as those of the John Deutsch Institute for the Study of Economic Policy
and our co-sponsors in this venture, to the authors and to Robert
Mundell
for their contributions to this volume.
It is a privilege and an enormous pleasure for me to invite you
to
sample our celebratory tribute to Robert Alexander Mundell, the 1999
Nobel
Laureate in Economic Sciences.